You know that saying “Don’t judge a book by its cover”? Well, I usually do jugde a book by its cover and I’d never have bought “Systemisches KONSENSIEREN” (“Systemic CONSENSUS”)! When a colleague dropped it on desk, I made fun of it – its whole appearance is “touchy-feely” in a bad way and, come on, CAPS? Really?
Fortunately, I picked the book up on a whim and its main (and only) idea immediately took the top position on my list of “things to try out”: When voting, don’t have the usual majority vote that generates winners and losers. Turn traditional voting upside down and determine least resistance!
Let me illustrate how that works with the first example in the book: There were 4 high-paid marketing people working on an ad campaign for a car. Everything was finished and decided, except for what color the car should have in the ad. They each strongly wanted a different color and majority vote always turned out like this:
Darkblue: | 1 |
Silver: | 1 |
Red: | 1 |
Black: | 1 |
Various attempts to agree among themselves were fruitless. Neither could they agree on whom else they might bring in to settle the matter. And the client said it was the professionals’ call. A deadlock.
Enter systemic consensus: Each of the 4 parties rates their rejection of each option on a scale from 0 (no resistance, I totally want this) to 10 (I’ll kill myself, if we take this). The result this time:
Marcia | Perry | Ana | Jack | Total Resistance | |
Darkblue: | 0 | 2 | 4 | 3 | 9 |
Silver: | 5 | 0 | 8 | 5 | 18 |
Red: | 7 | 4 | 0 | 6 | 17 |
Black: | 3 | 7 | 8 | 0 | 18 |
Yay, we’ve got a winner: Darkblue meets least resistance. Everyone can live with this color.
Given, in this simple case, they might have also reached a decision with an acceptance-based mechanisms finer grained than “1 vote only”. So why use “resistance” which rings negative with many people? Why not vote “acceptance” on a scale from 0 to 10?
Let me quote Diana Leafe Christian describing her first encounter with systemic consensus in something similar to a town hall meeting:
[…] I had trouble with “resistance” points. He [Ronald] helped me understand that they’re used for psychological, not mathematical reasons. If you ask people to think about why they want something, he said, they may not think about it as clearly as when you ask them why they don’t want it. If people have to ask themselves, “How much do I not want this?” — it forces them to better analyze the proposal.
The book states additional advantages as:
- Systemic consensus shifts focus from building alliances and “winning”, to incorporating the needs of others into your own proposals
- No one loses. The group wins.
- It makes sense to pick the option with least resistance, because it has the highest chances of actually being implemented by the group. (With majority vote I’ve often seen the defeated parties just ignoring the ruling.)
The authors claim that systemic consensus cannot be gamed by malicious parties. Their examples didn’t quite convince me. I’d need a lazy afternoon and my game theory hat to think about it in depth. Anyway, I’m usually not among malicious people and eager to give this a shot!
Do you want to know more?
- If you speak German, get the book or just google “systemisches konsensieren”.
- If you don’t speak German, read the blog post I already quoted or attend this Webinar on January 27th, 2012. (Disclaimer: I don’t know this Ronald guy. I just stumbled on the Webinar during research and thought it might be interesting.)
Do you have first hand experience with systemic consensus? How did it work out for you?